This article may rely excessively on sources too closely associated with the subject, potentially preventing the article from being verifiable and neutral. (January 2022) |
This article possibly contains original research. (July 2011) |
Schulze STV is a proposed multi-winner ranked voting system designed to achieve proportional representation.[1][2] It was invented by Markus Schulze, who developed the Schulze method for resolving ties using a Condorcet method. Schulze STV is similar to CPO-STV in that it compares possible winning candidate pairs and selects the Condorcet winner. It is named in analogy to the single transferable vote (STV), but only shares its aim of proportional representation, and is otherwise based on unrelated principles.
The system is based on Schulze's investigations into vote management and free riding.[3] When a voter prefers a popular candidate, there is an advantage to first choosing a candidate who is unlikely to win ("Woodall free riding") or omitting his preferred candidate from his rankings ("Hylland free riding"). Schulze STV is designed to be as resistant to free riding as possible, without giving up the Droop proportionality criterion.[1]
Example
editEach voter ranks candidates in their order of preference. In a hypothetical election, three candidates vie for two seats; Andrea and Carter represent the Yellow Party, and Brad represents the Purple Party. Andrea is a popular candidate, and has supporters who are not Yellow Party supporters. It is assumed that the Yellow Party can influence their own supporters, but not Andrea's.
There are 90 voters, and their preferences are
Andrea's
supporters |
Yellow Party
supporters |
Purple Party
supporters | ||
12 | 26 | 12 | 13 | 27 |
|
|
|
|
|
In the STV system, the initial tallies are:
- Andrea (Y): 50
- Carter (Y): 13
- Brad (P): 27
The quota is determined according to Andrea is declared elected and her surplus, , is distributed with
- Carter (Y):
- Brad (P):
Brad is also elected.
The Schulze STV system has three possible outcomes (sets of winners) in the election: Andrea and Carter, Andrea and Brad, and Carter and Brad. In this system, any candidate with more than the Droop quota of first choices will be elected. Andrea is certain to be elected, with two possible outcomes: Andrea and Carter, and Andrea and Brad.
Resistance to vote management
editIn vote management, a party instructs its voters not to rank a popular party candidate first. If the Yellow Party's leaders instruct their supporters to choose Carter first (followed by Andrea), the balloting changes. Unlike STV, however, Schulze STV resists vote management.[citation needed]
Potential for tactical voting
editProportional representation systems are much less susceptible to tactical voting than single-winner systems such as the first past the post system and instant-runoff voting (IRV), if the number of seats to be filled is sufficiently large.[citation needed] Schulze STV aims to have additional resistance to forms of tactical voting which are specific to single transferable voting methods, in particular a phenomenon that Schulze calls Hylland Free Riding.[1] STV methods which make use of Meek's or Warren's method are resistant to what Schulze calls Woodall Free Riding, but are still vulnerable to Hylland Free Riding.
As Schulze STV reduces to the Schulze method in single winner elections, it fails the participation criterion, the later-no-harm criterion and the later-no-help criterion, whereas traditional forms of STV (that reduce to IRV in single winner elections) fulfill later-no-help and later-no-harm.
Complexity
editSchulze STV is no more complicated for the voter than other forms of STV; the ballot is the same, and candidates are ranked in order of preference. In calculating an election result, however, Schulze STV is significantly more complex than STV. In most applications, computer calculation would be required. The algorithm implementing Schulze STV requires exponentially many steps in the number of seats to be filled (roughly on the order of steps when k out of m candidates are to be selected), making the computation difficult if this number is not very small. In particular, the rule does not have polynomial runtime.
Compared to CPO-STV, implementing Schulze STV might be somewhat faster, since it only compares outcomes differing by one candidate; CPO-STV compares all possible pairs.
References
edit- ^ a b c Markus Schulze (2011-03-11). "Free Riding and Vote Management under Proportional Representation by Single Transferable Vote" (PDF).
- ^ Markus Schulze (2017-03-10). "Implementing the Schulze STV Method".
- ^ Markus Schulze (June 2004). "Free Riding" (PDF). Voting matters (18): 2–8.
External links
edit- The Schulze Method of Voting (section 9) by Markus Schulze
- Python implementation